Gateway to Think Tanks
来源类型 | REPORT |
规范类型 | 报告 |
Fertile Ground | |
Ryan Richards; Mary Ellen Kustin; William Murray; Caroline Kitchens | |
发表日期 | 2018-02-05 |
出版年 | 2018 |
语种 | 英语 |
概述 | The farm bill is America's largest funding source for private lands conservation; its programs can be better leveraged to attract billions of dollars in private investment, increasing the economic and environmental benefits of conservation on working lands. |
摘要 | Introduction and summaryThe Dust Bowl was a watershed moment in American history—one of the earliest warning signs that the risks of poor environmental management can have spillover effects across society. In the 1930s, millions of tons of valuable soil were blown off the Great Plains, stripping agricultural potential from the region. Thousands of families lost their farms and were left to start over or join mass migrations to more promising parts of the country. The drought and dust storms laid bare the inextricable link between healthy lands and the health of a nation. For many, they were a wake-up call as to how poor land management practices can lead to devastating and far-reaching consequences for the economy, people, land, water, and wildlife. This realization resulted in a shift in how governments and businesses viewed their collective responsibility to the environment. For example, the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) implemented a soil conservation program in response to the Dust Bowl.1 Over the subsequent 80 years, the USDA also incorporated into its conservation efforts programs to conserve wildlife habitat, to use fertilizer more efficiently, and to protect wetlands and streams. These programs have helped prepare American agriculture for droughts and protect important ecosystems. Yet despite the widespread impacts of environmental issues on the nation’s health and economy, conservation efforts are chronically underfunded. Recent research suggests that, globally, about $300 billion in annual spending is necessary in order to maintain or restore the ecosystems and natural processes critical to human well-being.2 However, global philanthropic and government expenditures only amount to approximately $40 billion each year—well short of what is required.3 To avoid an experience akin to the post-Dust Bowl reckoning of the 1930s, policymakers need to expand how they think about conservation and conservation funding. One approach for growing the existing conservation funding pool is to engage businesses and attract private capital. Many private entities—from water utilities to Fortune 500 companies—directly benefit from clean water, clean air, and other environmental benefits that conservation can produce. Novel financial instruments, markets, and pay-for-success programs have the potential to engage these supportive groups—and attract billions of dollars in private investment to solve environmental problems—by providing incentives such as direct payments or cost savings to companies and landowners. The market potential exists; more than $1 billion in private capital has been invested in North American environmental markets since 2015.4 Still, an estimated $3 billion in additional capital is earmarked for conservation but on hold for projects that are ready for investment.5 Because these goods and services—clean air, clean water, and wildlife habitat—are often free and accessible to all, they are not something around which a market typically develops. As a result, government agencies have a particularly important role to play in developing innovative programs and policies to grow nascent markets and secure the services that landowners provide to consumers, companies, and the country by improving natural systems. This type of market has already emerged for certain types of environmental restoration, such as the wetland mitigation banking industry, and presents a way forward that will draw greater private investment into conservation on working lands. In the United States, the largest single source of public conservation funding comes from an unexpected piece of legislation: the farm bill. Although the bulk of the farm bill focuses on commodity subsidies and nutrition assistance, the most recent version allocated more than $5 billion in annual funding for various conservation programs.6 The farm bill is also a venue to set policy and pilot new programs that grow conservation on working lands in order to balance production of crops, timber, and livestock with environmental quality. For example, new efforts, such as the Regional Conservation Partnership Program, have used existing USDA conservation funds to leverage more than double their federal expenditures through collaborations with businesses and nongovernment organizations (NGOs).7 The next farm bill provides a unique opportunity to expand on this type of program and grow the pool of conservation funding. The Center for American Progress and the R Street Institute often approach policy challenges from different perspectives. However, we were inspired to work together on this report because we jointly recognize the scale of the conservation challenges that the nation faces—and the power of the farm bill to address them. The recommendations offered in this report provide a bipartisan approach that draws on measurable outcomes and market-based incentives to increase the social, economic, and environmental benefits of private lands conservation. We recommend several actions to leverage public funds to pull private investment off the sidelines and effectively double the impact of working lands programs under the conservation title. Specifically, the next iteration of the farm bill should do the following:
These actions have the potential to benefit businesses, landowners, and communities that are tied to the condition of agricultural and forested lands. The farm bill: America’s largest fund for conservationFocusing first on soil conservation in the 1930s, USDA conservation programs targeted a range of environmental issues by the 1980s.8 These included programs for soil and land conservation practices—preventing the loss of regionally important wetlands and topsoil—as well as restoration incentive programs that targeted specific species or habitats. Other programs focused on particular geographic areas, such as the Chesapeake Bay watershed.9 The most recent farm bill iteration, the Agricultural Act of 2014, simplified programs within the conservation title. These programs fall into three categories: land protection programs; incentive programs for conservation on working lands; and partnership programs.10 Land protection programs
Working lands programs
Partnership programs
Together, these programs provide roughly $5 billion annually in federal financial and technical assistance to interested landowners and have leveraged significant funding from outside government to make other investments in conservation. However, there is also significant unmet demand due to limited budgets; it is estimated that EQIP support has been awarded to an average of 30 percent of proposals in recent years because of funding constraints.16 Increasing the public benefits of private lands conservation and taking advantage of landowners’ desire to manage land for wildlife and natural resources will require funding support beyond what is currently available. Useful terms for conservation and environmental marketsEnvironmental services: The range of benefits provided through the functions of ecosystems, including water storage and filtration, soil retention and enrichment, and carbon sequestration. Habitat restoration: Land management activities conducted with the goal of returning some ecological function to an area and making it more suitable for wildlife. Examples range from prescribed burning in forests and rebuilding wetlands to removing aging dams. Pay for success: A contract model between multiple parties in which a payment is awarded only when the responsible party meets a desired social or environmental outcome.17 Environmental market: A market created in order to increase the provision of environmental goods or services. These are often driven by regulation and used as an alternative to fines or citations to secure the provision of ecosystem services or pollution abatement. For example, instead of reducing certain types of water pollution from a wastewater treatment plant through mandatory on-site renovations, an equal or greater amount of water quality improvement can be achieved through abatement elsewhere, such as through improved agricultural practices. This arrangement is organized by regulation, where seller reductions are certified by a third party or government agency and then purchased by the water treatment plant owners. The goal is to create incentives for pollution reduction at lower costs. Mitigation banking: The first pay-for-success model in the environmental field, conceived to give developers certainty that they can meet environmental regulations by compensating for development. Broadly speaking, mitigation banking is the purchase or management of land to create, restore, or preserve a quantifiable amount of wetland, stream, or species habitat. It can also act as an ecosystem function—such as water quality or flow—that can be sold as credits to other parties to mitigate environmental impacts elsewhere. The most common form is wetland mitigation banking, in which private firms or NGOs purchase and/or create wetland features to sell as credits that compensate for environmental damage from development elsewhere. Species mitigation banking—in which land is managed to provide a habitat for species conservation—has become increasingly common.18 A primer on paying for performanceAddressing the scale of conservation problems means confronting significant challenges—namely, enticing additional investment and ensuring that existing funds provide the greatest conservation benefit. Private capital is one option for expanding the investment pool, but financial risk—the possibility that an investment will not generate a return—limits interest. Government agencies do not require a financial return on investment, but constituents and policymakers have an interest in maximizing the social and environmental return on conservation funding. If payments are made before a good or service is delivered, there is a risk that delivery will not occur. This creates a performance risk that affects funders’ willingness to support a project. ![]() A pay-for-success approach can help address both financial and performance risk. The model works by structuring the payment to occur after some desired outcome has been achieved rather than having the payment occur at the start of a project or for inputs. This structure is often simple—someone receives a payment based on improvements in one outcome—but complex structures have also been proposed, with graduated payments based on a range of outcomes or on incremental gains in one outcome. This creates the potential for financial returns that are attractive to private investors and guarantees a social or environmental return for the public. The theory is that basing rewards on outcomes will encourage program participants—either a target group of landowners or investors collaborating with those landowners—to find effective ways to meet goals that otherwise would not have been pursued. Linking incentives to performance has been tested in a variety of settings to find cost savings and spur innovation that can be more widely adopted. Benefits of a pay-for-success model
Social policy programs have been a major focus of existing pay-for-success efforts. Pay for success has been piloted in several states to find new ways of providing better delivery of services, such as health care and education, or to reduce negative social outcomes, including recidivism. South Carolina, for example, uses a pay-for-success model to increase health care outcomes under the state’s policy objectives for mothers and children. The program rewards investments that make health care more accessible for low-income parents by tying payments to observed reductions in the rates of pre-term births and other health metrics.19 The state will monitor other long-term metrics such as school performance to determine the social value of the program. The pay-for-success model is intended to extend the reach of health services—which are critically important for young children—and to help participants overcome barriers to access. In the environmental field, there are several examples of incentives being used to attract investments in the procurement of ecosystem services. These include pay-for-success contracts for specific projects—sometimes referred to as green or environmental impact bonds—and regulation-driven markets, where the measured environmental gains of a project are converted into credits that can be sold to mitigate for environmental impacts elsewhere. For example:
How pay-for-success and market-based models can advance USDA conservation objectivesUSDA conservation programs already have characteristics that align with pay-for-success initiatives, which creates an easier path to finding opportunities to utilize this approach. These shared traits include the use of positive incentives and voluntary participation, as well as a focus on measurable environmental metrics that can be used to set outcomes. Given their focus on private lands conservation, USDA conservation programs have tended to focus on providing rewards rather than punishment to encourage landowner participation. While this approach is appealing, it also raises valid questions over the optimal structure programs can take to maximize their environmental benefits. When allocating contracts, land protection programs consider the potential environmental benefits of retiring land temporarily or permanently, while partnership-focused initiatives, such as the RCPP, create space for projects with outcome-focused incentives.25 Linking landowner payments to measured, demonstrable improvements on working lands would guarantee a public benefit. This opportunity to use measurable outcomes aligns with broader, bipartisan efforts to collect and use data to improve policies.26 Pay for success also complements ongoing research efforts by the USDA and its partners to understand the links between land management and environmental services. This research has helped shape metrics, such as acres of habitat or tons of avoided nutrient runoff from agricultural fields, that can be measured as outcomes. This helps utilities, businesses, and government agencies gain confidence in the value of investing in environmental services and drives demand for landowners to provide them. In June 2017, for example, a group of Arkansas rice farmers, with the support of the USDA and environmental NGOs, became the first rice producers to generate and sell carbon credits for measurable reductions in methane emissions through rice production.27 Methane is a powerful greenhouse gas that rice fields often emit when they are flooded. Models of greenhouse gas emissions from rice fields were used to identify by how much methane emissions would be reduced if fields were periodically dried. Farmers who adopted this practice received carbon credits for their efforts. Their improved land management practices became a marketable asset, and they sold the credits they generated to Microsoft Corp. as the company sought to compensate for its own emissions. Practical challenges for performance-based programsSeveral factors affect the potential of pay for success to improve existing conservation programs. These factors include structuring incentives to appeal to landowners and targeting investments to ensure that benefits exceed costs. Such limitations will affect how and where the concept of pay for success could be a useful part of USDA conservation programs. Voluntary conservation programs—pay for success or otherwise—need to be attractive enough for desired participants to enroll. Barriers to enrollment can stem from a range of factors, including the design of incentive payments; uncertainty about the likelihood of a payout, or the odds that a landowner can meet the requirements for success; the transaction costs, including the time, energy, and investment necessary to participate; and access to the technical and financial resources that help with participation. Pay-for-success programs can be more complex than simple enrollment programs such as the Conservation Reserve Program or EQIP, so these factors need to be carefully considered and understood. Regulatory certainty can have a range of effects on both pay-for-success and environmental markets, as regulation affects investments. For example, it can affect how a business will reduce carbon emissions or whether restoring habitat will generate credits that can be sold as mitigation. Changing or even threatening to change the regulatory environment shifts the range of risks that landowners and investors have to consider. While some regulations have created stability, such as in the wetlands mitigation banking market, this is not always the case. In March 2017, for example, U.S. Interior Secretary Ryan Zinke ordered a review of policies regarding the use of mitigation to aid in the recovery of endangered species.28 Later that year, he directed the department to review and possibly transform management plans for the greater sage-grouse and rescinded departmental guidance for reducing the impact of development on public land.29 These policies and plans were important guidance for private investment in mitigation banks for threatened species, many of which took years to develop.30 Even if the policies remain largely intact, the revision process may have long-term consequences for the voluntary conservation of threatened species. Regulatory uncertainty makes it clear that while the costs of conservation are guaranteed, returns are not.31 Finally, the demand for the provision of ecosystem services will affect pay-for-success or performance-based conservation efforts. Over the past decade, a great deal of effort has been focused on attracting additional investment into conservation. Successes are evident in some contexts, including, for example, utilities’ investments in watershed management.32 However, demand for other environmental benefits, such as carbon storage and sequestration and habitat conservation for threatened species, remains limited. Regulatory changes or other economic triggers may change this trend, but until then, coordination problems may limit market development. In light of these limitations, a pay-for-success approach would likely require the following conditions to add value to existing programs:
With these principles in mind, there are several ways that the 2018 farm bill can help th |
主题 | Energy and Environment |
URL | https://www.americanprogress.org/issues/green/reports/2018/02/05/445815/fertile-ground/ |
来源智库 | Center for American Progress (United States) |
资源类型 | 智库出版物 |
条目标识符 | http://119.78.100.153/handle/2XGU8XDN/436708 |
推荐引用方式 GB/T 7714 | Ryan Richards,Mary Ellen Kustin,William Murray,et al. Fertile Ground. 2018. |
条目包含的文件 | 条目无相关文件。 |
除非特别说明,本系统中所有内容都受版权保护,并保留所有权利。