G2TT
来源类型VoxEU Column
规范类型评论
Why policies may need to be place-based in order to be people-centred
Jose Enrique Garcilazo; Joaquim Oliveira Martins; William Tompson
发表日期2010-11-20
出版年2010
语种英语
摘要How much influence did colonisation have on Africa’s development? This column examines data from before colonisation up to the modern day and argues that differences in colonial institutions do not explain differences in regional economic performance. Instead, it finds that pre-colonial political centralisation and ethnic class stratification have a significantly positive impact on local development.
正文

The conventional wisdom on the deep determinants of African development places colonisation at the centre of any explanation. An influential body of research suggests that the extractive colonial institutions that Europeans established in the late 19th century, crucially contributed to African underdevelopment. This channel invokes the lack of checks and balances on the executive and the poorly performing legal systems that endured after African independence (Acemoglu et al. 2005). But European interference in the continent took several other forms.

The slave trades during the 15th-19th century, for example, also hindered its subsequent economic performance (Nunn 2008). Moreover, the artificial border design seems to have played a negative role by increasing the degree of ethnic fragmentation and spurring civil conflict (Englebert et al. 2001, Alesina et al. 2010). Yet some African scholars downplay the importance of colonial and even contemporary institutional structures and stress the role of deeply rooted historically determined ethnic characteristics. Anecdotal evidence, case studies, and a few academic works show that ethnic-specific institutional and cultural characteristics matter, even today (Herbst 2001, Dowden 2006, Gennaioli and Rainer 2007). The ethnic institutional structures become salient as most African states characterised by limited state capacity are unable to provide public goods, collect taxes, and enforce contracts (Acemoglu 2005, Besley and Persson 2009). For example tribal chiefs, rather than national judges tend to resolve disputes, especially in the African country side. Moreover, local chiefs rather than state bureaucrats collect taxes, enforce property rights, and provide public goods.

In our recent paper (Michalopoulos and Papaioannou 2010), we examine the effect on comparative development of national contemporary institutional structures and ethnicity-specific pre-colonial institutional traits. To advance on the causality front we develop a methodological approach that combines anthropological data on the spatial distribution of ethnicities before colonisation, historical information on some key ethnic institutional/cultural traits, and contemporary light density image data from satellites as a proxy of regional development. Figure 1a illustrates the historical homelands of the major ethnicities spanning the African landscape in the eve of colonisation. Figure 1b plots satellite density across each tribal area. One observation that becomes immediately obvious is the significant variation in the degree of luminosity across regions.

Figure 1a.

Figure 1b.

Contemporary national institutions and regional development

To identify the one-way effect of contemporary national institutions on regional development we exploit in a quasi-experimental econometric setting the so-called “scramble of Africa” in the late 19th century. The partitioning of Africa started with the Berlin Conference of 1884-1885 that established the principles on how Europeans would split Africa into spheres of influence, protectorates, free-trade areas, and colonies and was completed by the beginning of the 20th century. Crucially the borders that Europeans draw in the map in Berlin, London, Brussels, and Paris at a time when they had not even settled Africa, endured after independence in the 1960s. As a result of this arbitrary border drawing, hundreds of ethnic groups were partitioned into more than one state, thus subjecting identical cultures to different country-level formal institutions.

We make use of this historical accident. We compare economic performance as proxied by satellite light density at night in regions belonging to the historical homeland of the same ethnic group, but fall into two (or more) countries that have national institutions of different quality.

Our approach required identifying partitioned ethnicities. To identify split groups we combine George Peter Murdock’s (1959) Ethnolingusitic Map that portrays the spatial distribution of 835 ethnicities before colonisation (Figure 1) with the Digital Chart of the World that delineates contemporary political boundaries. Our procedure identifies most ethnicities that case studies and anecdotal evidence suggest that have been partitioned by the political boundaries (see Figure 2). For example, the Maasai have been partitioned between Kenya and Tanzania (shares 62% and 38% respectively), the Anyi between Ghana and the Ivory Coast (shares 58% and 42%), and the Chewa between Mozambique (50%), Malawi (34%), and Zimbabwe (16%).

Figure 2.

Our econometric (regression discontinuity) approach compares economic performance (as reflected in luminosity density) in the historical homeland of the Anyi in Ghana with that in the adjacent region in the Ivory Coast where the Anyi also reside. We also do the study for the Maasai between Kenya and Tanzania. This “matching” type approach that focuses on adjacent by the border regions belonging to the historical homeland of the same ethnicity allows us to account for hard-to-measure cultural features (related to trust, religion, societal habits) that correlate significantly with both economic wellbeing and sound institutions. Moreover by focusing on nearby areas we account effectively for geography, the disease environment, and other ecological features; this is fundamental as many influential scholars argue that both institutional and economic development are driven by geographic-ecological difference (Sachs 2005).

In line with casual empiricism we find that regional development is higher in ethnic areas with better functioning national institutions – as reflected in a composite rule of law index that captures effectiveness of the judiciary and the quality of property rights protection as well as the control of corruption.1 Yet our within-ethnicity results show that there is no systematic relationship between country-wide differences in institutions and tribal economic performance (see Figures 3a, 3b). This result casts doubt on the causal interpretation of the cross-country positive correlation between countrywide institutional quality and economic development in Africa.

Figure 3a. Does corruption matter?

Figure 3b. Does rule of law matter?


Pre-colonial ethnic institutions and regional development

We then examine the effect of deep historical ethnicity-specific institutional characteristics on African development utilising two measures from the pioneering work of George Peter Murdock (1967), who through extensive field work and research, has produced a database of quantitative measures of cultural, economic, and institutional characteristics of African ethnicities at the time of colonisation. Figures 4a and 4b portray the vast heterogeneity in political centralisation and ethnic class stratification across African ethnicities. The political centralisation index ranges from 0 to 4, reflecting the number of jurisdictional hierarchies above the local community level for each society. Previous work suggests that by increasing the accountability of local chiefs, politically centralised societies can achieve better economic outcomes (Gannaioli and Rainer 2007). Examples of large ethnicities without any level of political organisation above the village level include the Bura and the Lango in Uganda. Examples of tribes belonging to small chiefdoms are the Mende in Sierra Leone and the Ibo of Nigeria. The Mbundu in Angola and the Zerma in Niger are examples of societies that are part of large paramount chiefdoms, while the Yoruba in Nigeria, the Mossi in Burkina Faso and the Kafa in Ethiopia are parts of large states. As with the jurisdictional hierarchy measure, there was significant heterogeneity in class stratification across Africa at the time of colonisation. Highly stratified societies (with complex distinctions) include the Yoruba and the Nupe in Nigeria, while examples of ethnicities without wealth or elite distinctions are the Maasai in Kenya and Tanzania, the Chewa in Malawi, and the Songo in Angola.

Figure 4a.

Figure 4b.

主题Development ; Institutions and economics ; Politics and economics
关键词Development Growth Africa Institutions Culture
URLhttps://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/why-policies-may-need-be-place-based-order-be-people-centred
来源智库Centre for Economic Policy Research (United Kingdom)
资源类型智库出版物
条目标识符http://119.78.100.153/handle/2XGU8XDN/548595
推荐引用方式
GB/T 7714
Jose Enrique Garcilazo,Joaquim Oliveira Martins,William Tompson. Why policies may need to be place-based in order to be people-centred. 2010.
条目包含的文件
条目无相关文件。
个性服务
推荐该条目
保存到收藏夹
导出为Endnote文件
谷歌学术
谷歌学术中相似的文章
[Jose Enrique Garcilazo]的文章
[Joaquim Oliveira Martins]的文章
[William Tompson]的文章
百度学术
百度学术中相似的文章
[Jose Enrique Garcilazo]的文章
[Joaquim Oliveira Martins]的文章
[William Tompson]的文章
必应学术
必应学术中相似的文章
[Jose Enrique Garcilazo]的文章
[Joaquim Oliveira Martins]的文章
[William Tompson]的文章
相关权益政策
暂无数据
收藏/分享

除非特别说明,本系统中所有内容都受版权保护,并保留所有权利。