G2TT
来源类型VoxEU Column
规范类型评论
The “Seoul Consensus” on development: Substantial progress for sub-Saharan Africa or paperwork again?
Matthias Bauer; Peter Draper; Andreas Freytag
发表日期2011-04-15
出版年2011
语种英语
摘要Conventional wisdom states that financial globalisation has been advancing since the mid-1980s, particularly in developing countries. It also states that this should have fostered international portfolio diversification and consumption smoothing. But this column takes a closer look at the data and argues that neither financial globalisation nor portfolio diversification has grown significantly in emerging markets over that period.
正文

De facto financial globalisation is typically measured a proxy consisting of the ratio of cross-border assets and liabilities (averaged) over GDP. Based on data on cross-border holdings compiled by Lane and Milessi Ferreti (2007), this measure indicates that:

  • Financial globalisation in emerging markets has been lagging that in more advanced markets;
  • It has been driven by FDI (and, more recently, equities) at the expense of debt liabilities;
  • In advanced economies, it is still largely dominated by debt securities (see Figure 11) .

Figure 1. Financial globalisation measures: Emerging markets vs. others

Note: PCE (peripheral core economies): Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden. G5: France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the U.S. Figures shows country group averages of de facto financial globalisation measures over GDP and de jure measure of financial globalisation for balanced panel data. Only countries with complete data from 1990 to 2007 were used. Source: LMF (2008), WDI, Chinn-Ito.

The last point is more clearly seen by comparing changes in gross foreign positions (Figure 2). The marked decline in debt liabilities (coupled with the build-up of reserves) due to the sovereign deleveraging process in emerging markets contrasts with the growing net debt of G5 countries. More generally, though, Figures 1 and 2 indicate that aggregate financial-globalisation-to-GDP ratios have been growing across the board.

Figure 2. From 1999 to 2007: merging Markets vs. others

Note: Figures presents changes of de facto financial globalisation measures from LMF (2008) over GDP. Countries in this figure are the same as in F1a. Changes are from 1999 to 2007. Source: LMF (2007), WDI.

For a number of reasons, however, a normalisation by the capitalisation of the local market (marcap) seems more appropriate.

  • For starters, the role of cross-border holdings and flows as a source of international contagion and exogenous price volatility should be a function of their size relative to the host market.
  • Moreover, an increasing financial-globalisation-to-GDP, rather than a sign of growing globalisation as it is typically interpreted, could instead be the reflection of a deepening of local markets, regardless of the pattern of foreign participation.

In turn, much of this local market “deepening” may be mechanically driven by valuation changes, due to the equity rally and the real appreciation in emerging markets prior to the 2008 crisis (Levy Yeyati 2011).

As Figure 3 shows, local markets size indeed played a central role in explaining the rising financial-globalisation-to-GDP ratios. For example, 7% out of the 10% increase in equity foreign liabilities is explained by an increase in marcap over GDP, which suggests that, rather than leading the deepening of local equity markets, foreign investors may have accompanied the growth in market capitalisation due to higher equity prices.

Figure 3. Financial globalisation and different normalisations: Merging markets vs. others

Note: Figures presents changes foreign equity/debt liabilities divided by market capitalization/Total Debt or GDP. Changes are from 1999 to 2007. Source: LMF (2007), WDI, BIS.

Financial globalisation and international risk sharing

In theory, countries with greater financial globalisation should reduce consumption relative to output volatility through international risk sharing. However, recent empirical studies have failed to validate this premise.2

The degree of risk sharing can be proxied by “consumption betas” estimated by the slope of per capita consumption to output growth, both taken as deviations from world levels.

As Figure 4 shows, estimated consumption betas are negatively correlated with financial-globalisation-to-GDP ratios for the advanced-markets sample, but the link is not significant (and of the opposite sign) for emerging markets –in line with the disappointing results reported in Kose et al. (2007).

Figure 4. Risk sharing: Consumption betas vs. financial globalisation

Development ; International Finance
关键词Development Globalisation Emerging markets International finance
URLhttps://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/seoul-consensus-development-substantial-progress-sub-saharan-africa-or-paperwork
来源智库Centre for Economic Policy Research (United Kingdom)
资源类型智库出版物
条目标识符http://119.78.100.153/handle/2XGU8XDN/548818
推荐引用方式
GB/T 7714
Matthias Bauer,Peter Draper,Andreas Freytag. The “Seoul Consensus” on development: Substantial progress for sub-Saharan Africa or paperwork again?. 2011.
条目包含的文件
条目无相关文件。
个性服务
推荐该条目
保存到收藏夹
导出为Endnote文件
谷歌学术
谷歌学术中相似的文章
[Matthias Bauer]的文章
[Peter Draper]的文章
[Andreas Freytag]的文章
百度学术
百度学术中相似的文章
[Matthias Bauer]的文章
[Peter Draper]的文章
[Andreas Freytag]的文章
必应学术
必应学术中相似的文章
[Matthias Bauer]的文章
[Peter Draper]的文章
[Andreas Freytag]的文章
相关权益政策
暂无数据
收藏/分享

除非特别说明,本系统中所有内容都受版权保护,并保留所有权利。